Physicians Treating Physicians: Relational and Informational Advantages in Treatment and Survival
Abstract
We use the medical specialties of physician-patients with advanced cancer to study the role of knowledge versus networks in treatment choices and patient survival by matching comparable patients with doctors and admission periods to control unobserved doctor quality. Physician-patients are less likely to have surgery, radiation, or checkups and more likely to receive targeted therapy, spend more on drugs, enjoy a higher survival rate, and spend less on coinsurance than nonphysician-patients. Knowledge mechanisms play a crucial role because the network effect explains some, but not all, patterns. For less informed physician-patients, possessing a network is equivalent to reducing medical knowledge.
I. Introduction
A growing body of literature in labor economics is devoted to examining whether complete information or robust social ties can solve agency problems (Bandiera, Barankay, and Rasul 2009; Jackson and Schneider 2011). Health economists join this empirical investigation by randomizing doctors’ races and vaccine incentives for patients (Alsan, Garrick, and Graziani 2019) or exploiting the exogenous variation of obstetrics and gynecology (OB/GYN) doctors’ rotating call schedules in doctor-patient clinical relationships (Johnson et al. 2016). Their findings show that communication and patients’ trust in physicians strongly affect their demand for preventive care (Alsan, Garrick, and Graziani 2019) or a cesarean section (Johnson et al. 2016). Both studies addressed unobserved doctor quality and the problem of patient selection using compelling research designs.
Besides experimental or quasi-experimental designs, observational studies have examined whether physician-mothers are more or less likely than nonphysician-mothers to undergo a cesarean section with mixed results.1 Grytten, Skau, and Sørensen (2011) found that physician-mothers received a cesarean section more often, perhaps because of a closer relationship or better communication with their attending doctor. Conversely, Chou et al. (2006) and Johnson and Rehavi (2016) found that physician-mothers are less likely to undergo a cesarean section, perhaps because they know about the potential complications or side effects. Irrespective of underuse due to weak social ties or overuse due to asymmetric information, the relational and informational disadvantages are empirically inseparable, relying merely on one medical specialty.
The importance of the relational and informational influences on health-care agency issues is evaluated in this paper by studying Taiwanese inpatient doctors with a range of first/main specialties who have attended about 0.4 million patients with advanced cancer since 2004, including hundreds of physician-patients. These specialists must regularly attend Taiwan Oncology Society (TOS) conferences and training courses to maintain their oncology subspecialty licenses. We exploit the TOS’s taxonomy to identify the professional ties between each physician-patient and attending doctor. Meanwhile, we quantify each physician-patient’s medical knowledge of the diagnosed cancer by calculating the cancer caseload given their specialty and hospital department. By matching physician-patients with different specialties treated by the same doctor, we distinguish the effects of relational advantage (due to stronger professional ties) and informational advantage (due to being more informed).
Because of a lack of experimental variation, we address unobserved physician quality and patient selection issues using Abadie and Imbens’s (2006, 2011) nearest-neighbor matching method, which facilitates complex interactions among covariates without linearity assumptions. Our approach exploits the within-doctor-hospital variation across patients treated during the same period, matched by factors such as gender, cancer sites, income levels, and previous inpatient costs. This strategy enables us to minimize the bias from high-quality doctors being more likely to attend physician-patients.
Before evaluating relational and informational advantages, we follow the literature to compare physician-patients’ treatment choices and survival rates with those of nonphysician-patients. Our matching estimates show that the average physician-patient is less likely than others to choose surgical/radiation therapies and more likely to use targeted drug therapy. Physician-patients also spend less on checkups and enjoy significantly higher survival rates. The magnitude ranges from 0.2 to 0.4 standard deviations, all statistically significant at the conventional level.
These basic results conform to relational/informational mechanisms and competing explanations, such as the early diagnosis and treatment of physician-patients. We rule out both competing hypotheses empirically. Doctors in the universal cancer registry are equally likely to detect cancer in early or advanced stages for physicians- and nonphysician-patients. Our matching estimates also show no difference in the diagnosis-to-treatment interval between these two types of patients. Based on our data, these empirical results suggest that doctors do not diagnose or treat physician-patients sooner than others.
Another possible reason for the lower intensive care utilization we found among physician-patients is that nonphysician-patients are more likely to sue. Doctors may prescribe unnecessary procedures for less informed patients to reduce their potential liability. But Taiwan’s medical liability literature shows that most lawsuits arise from neurosurgery, anesthesiology, and the emergency room (ER; Chen et al. 2012). We found that almost no patients visited these hospital departments for cancer care, suggesting that our results are unlikely to be due to unequal propensity to sue.
Beyond the basic results, we exploit the proposed measures of network and knowledge to explore the mechanisms behind the average physician-patient effects. We compare nonphysician-patients to physician-patients with no professional ties or specialist knowledge of the diagnosed cancer site and find physician superiority leads to different treatments but not higher survival rates. When restricted to physician-patients only, we find that although a professional tie does not affect short-term survival, it improves long-term survival by promoting intensive care (i.e., surgical/radiation therapies) at extensive margins. However, why typical physician-patients utilize more targeted therapy and less intensive care at extensive margins while enjoying significantly better short-term survival cannot be explained by either physician superiority or professional networks, leaving information mechanism as a likely explanation for physician-patients’ short-term survival benefits and treatment patterns.
Our further investigation reveals that professional networks and knowledge are interchangeable if physician-patients are less informed. We impose functional form assumptions on comparable physician-patients to quantify their informational interchangeability for professional ties. For those with knowledge in the bottom quartile, a network would be equivalent to a reduction of 6–18 percentage points in specialist knowledge to maintain the same survival level or treatment intensity. This finding implies a potential scenario where attending doctors abuse patients’ trust by prescribing different procedures than they would for more informed patients. Such a deviation can harm patients’ survival. This result confirms the dominant role of information over professional ties in treatment choice and survival, particularly for patients who lack expert knowledge.2
Our assessment of relational and informational mechanisms contributes a new dimension to the literature on health-care agency problems. Previous researchers primarily focused on doctor-driven channels, including financial incentives and asymmetric information. Instead, we address both channels by looking within matched sets of physician-patients who specialize in various medical areas and are treated by the same doctor. The findings demonstrate that the doctor-patient relationship matters for treatment choice and long-term survival at an advanced cancer stage because it generates more information for informed patients. Also, we demonstrate that information plays a dominant role for less informed patients. For relational and informational mechanisms to work, the theoretical context must include a doctor-driven demand hypothesis via a framework in which risk-averse patients undervalue the benefit of intensive care, thereby reducing demand. A stronger doctor-patient relationship can overcome risk aversion with better communication and trust building to stimulate demand, but it can also give doctors leeway to abuse their patients’ trust and deviate from appropriate care.
The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section II describes our data sources, institutional settings, and descriptive statistics. Section III descried our matching scheme to construct the study sample, balance statistics, core estimates, and robustness checks. Alternative explanations for our findings are provided in section IV. The possible mechanisms are explored in section V by extending our research to contrast the relational and informational roles of treatment intensity and survival rates. The paper is concluded in section VI.
II. Data and Institutional Settings
A. Patient Cost Sharing and Provider Reimbursement
Taiwan’s National Health Insurance (NHI) database is ideal for this study for several reasons. First, similar to Canada, the Taiwanese NHI is a single-payer system for all citizens and residents consisting of a uniform, comprehensive care benefits package that covers drugs, hospitals, and primary care (Chen and Chuang 2016). Since participation in the NHI is mandatory, we can eliminate doubts about adverse selection issues. Furthermore, we can address patient selection issues because the database includes beneficiaries who have never been in the hospital.
The NHI administration manages health expenditure inflation by reimbursing providers rather than charging deductibles or capping out-of-pocket expenses. This form of reimbursement is fee-for-service via a uniform national fee schedule to prevent providers from selecting patients or imposing price discrimination on them. Since hospitals pay doctors on a fee-for-service basis plus a basic salary that varies across hospitals, the financial incentives of doctors and hospitals are similar.
Moreover, the NHI system imposes a minor penalty (only US$7 in 2014) on hospital visits without primary care referrals. Consequently, almost all patients choose their attending doctor without a primary care referral. As patients can freely check into different hospitals or request different doctors in the same hospital, we analyze doctor-patient relationships by examining hospital admissions data. Taiwanese hospitals work on a closed-staff structure, with the on-staff doctor assuming full responsibility for patient care. This institutional setting ensures that matching patients to physicians can precisely describe the interaction between doctors and patients during hospital admissions.
B. Data Linkage
We merge several administrative data sources in the NHI database from 2000 to 2018 using unique scrambled identifiers (IDs) via four steps. First, we link the Cancer Registry to the Death Registry and the Registry of Beneficiaries. This data link covers cancer patients’ diagnosis date(s), cancer site(s), and diagnosis stage. It also documents treatment methods, demographic background (sex, birthday, income bracket, and registration district), death records if patients died by the end of 2019, and whether they received hospital care.
Second, we identify the physician-patients and obtain their medical specialties by merging the data with the Registry for Medical Personnel and Records of Board-Certified Specialists using their IDs. The former covers physician gender, birthday, and certification date, and the latter records their medical specialties and practice locations over time. Third, we combine the above data with the Reimbursement Claim Records to obtain inpatient care details per hospital admission 1 year after a cancer diagnosis. These data reveal the entire history of treatments, care volumes, hospital type and location, hospital ID, and attending doctor’s ID so that we can calculate the total inpatient care costs, coinsurance payments, and spending on medicines, surgery, tube feeding, radiation therapy, and examination to construct covariates and outcome variables. Finally, we again use the attending doctor’s ID to derive his or her certified specialty and experience by linking the compiled data to the Registry for Medical Personnel and Records of Board-Certified Specialists.
C. Time-Varying Doctor Selectivity
Like physicians’ experience, doctor selectivity can vary over time. We estimate an expert patient’s knowledge of doctor selectivity at the time of diagnosis using the percentage of physician-patient hospital admissions 3 years before. For instance, if a doctor attended 1,000 hospital admissions in the past 3 years and only two were physician-patients, the selectivity measure takes a value of 0.002. While the public knows about physicians’ experience, doctor selectivity is typically not well known except to expert patients.
Doctors chosen by physician-patients are twice as selective as those chosen by other patients, with a selectivity level of 0.0039 (), as shown in table 1. Moreover, physician-patients select more experienced doctors than nonphysician-patients by 2 years. These are large and statistically significant differences at the 95% level.
Variable | End-Stage Cancer at First Diagnosis | p-value | |
---|---|---|---|
Nonphysicians Mean | Physicians Minus Nonphysicians | ||
Patient attributes: | |||
Male | .50 | .35 | .000 |
Age at the first diagnosis | 57.76 | 1.96 | .026 |
Log income at the first diagnosis | 10.05 | .89 | .000 |
Log previous hospital spending | 4.09 | −.72 | .015 |
Preexisting clinical relationship with attending | .07 | −.01 | .221 |
Doctor attributes: | |||
Male | .88 | .03 | .049 |
Experience at admission | 12.77 | 2.06 | .000 |
Selectivity at first diagnosis | .0022 | .0017 | .000 |
Practice in multiple hospitals | .43 | −.07 | .003 |
Specialty unrelated to cancer treatment | .08 | −.02 | .062 |
Hospital types: | |||
Teaching | .21 | .12 | .000 |
Veteran | .16 | .13 | .000 |
Private | .61 | −.14 | .000 |
Acute inpatient stays (days) | 7.89 | −.81 | .023 |
Diagnosis-to-treatment interval | 122.66 | −5.59 | .072 |
Cancer care and therapy: | |||
Surgery | .66 | −.05 | .073 |
Chemotherapy | .80 | −.04 | .070 |
Radiation therapy | .32 | −.01 | .652 |
Targeted therapy | .11 | .05 | .029 |
Palliative care | .15 | −.04 | .030 |
Log spending: | |||
Total NHI cost | 10.50 | .03 | .552 |
Coinsurance | .66 | .16 | .010 |
NHI drugs | 8.67 | −.07 | .467 |
Surgery | 2.29 | .06 | .617 |
Tube feeding | .56 | −.16 | .003 |
Radiation therapy | 7.10 | −.33 | .001 |
Examination | 6.84 | −.04 | .758 |
Survival: | |||
Lived ≥180 days | .93 | .01 | .321 |
Lived ≥365 days | .81 | .07 | .000 |
Lived ≥1,095 days | .55 | .10 | .004 |
A significant challenge of our empirical work is that doctors could become more selective as they gain experience. As a result, patients treated earlier are not necessarily comparable to those treated later by the same doctor. To remove this time-varying bias, we fix the attending doctor and admission time for a fair comparison.
D. Descriptive Statistics
Table A1 compares the characteristics of physician-patients to those of nonphysician-patients, including their demographics, inpatient care receipt, and survival outcomes. The data comprise more than 1.2 million cancer diagnoses, approximately 1 million patients, and 1,987 medical doctors. The number of cancer diagnoses exceeds that of cancer patients because a single patient can be diagnosed more than once for recurrence or confirmation. Only 0.01% of diagnoses involve multiple cancers. Thirty percent of all cancers first diagnosed from January 2004 to December 2016 were in the advanced stage.3 The data period began in January 2004, when Taiwan began to adopt the AJCC Cancer Staging Manual, the benchmark for classifying cancer patients. Our analysis covers all of the cancer sites listed in table 2.
ICD-O-3 Code | Cancer Site | I. Medical Oncology | I and II | II. Surgical Oncology | Not Listed by TOS | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Internal Medicine (1) | Nuclear Medicine (2) | Radiation Oncology (3) | OB/GYN (4) | Surgery (5) | Urology (6) | Orthopedics (7) | Otorhinolaryngology (8) | Dermatology (9) | Ophthalmology (10) | ||
C74–C75 | Adrenal or other endocrine glands | .033 | .694 | .019 | .011 | .103 | .013 | .008 | .084 | .009 | .012 |
C70–C72, C80 | Brain/nerves or unknown | .118 | .025 | .273 | .230 | .208 | .053 | .023 | .131 | .030 | .016 |
C51–C58 | Female genital organs | .029 | .011 | .091 | .703 | .024 | .022 | .010 | .008 | .009 | .007 |
C50 | Breast | .084 | .004 | .190 | .015 | .490 | .008 | .018 | .005 | .006 | .005 |
C64–C68 | Urinary tract | .073 | .029 | .119 | .023 | .029 | .883 | .025 | .013 | .013 | .013 |
C40–C41 | Bone or articular cartilage | .552 | .212 | .112 | .101 | .058 | .294 | .106 | |||
C00–C14 | Lip/pharynx or oral cavity | .053 | .005 | .166 | .004 | .033 | .006 | .006 | .333 | .005 | .004 |
C44 | Skin | .115 | .146 | .046 | .220 | .073 | .074 | .129 | .576 | .114 | |
C69 | Eye | .328 | .214 | .161 | .277 | 1.000 | |||||
C60–C63 | Male genital organs | .080 | .134 | .064 | .050 | .916 | .049 | .026 | .058 | .034 | |
C47, C49 | Malignant neoplasm of peripheral nerves and autonomic nervous systems or other connective and soft tissues | .289 | .229 | .170 | .146 | .092 | .234 | .093 | .092 | ||
C30–C39 | Respiratory and intrathoracic organs | .218 | .007 | .200 | .014 | .101 | .016 | .016 | .096 | .014 | .007 |
C15, C16, C48 | Esophagus, intestinal tract, retroperitoneum, or peritoneum | .098 | .015 | .208 | .017 | .191 | .015 | .016 | .012 | .004 | .004 |
M95903–M99933a | Leukemia | .091 | .013 | .218 | .006 | .011 | .009 | .007 | .018 | .011 | .008 |
Notably, statistics indicate that 12% of patients diagnosed with cancer need no hospital care. About a quarter of these are in the advanced stage (not shown in the table). After controlling the interaction of patient demographics, prior medical spending, and admission year, we find that physician-patients are significantly more likely to receive hospital care by 1 percentage point (with a standard error of 0.006; not reported in the table). This difference was statistically insignificant and decreased when limiting the sample to advanced-stage cancer at the first diagnosis.
Each cancer diagnosis was likely to lead to more cancer therapies, including surgery, chemotherapy, radiation therapy, palliative care, targeted therapy, hormone therapy, immunotherapy, stem cell treatment, and Chinese medicine. We excluded the last three from our main analysis because less than 1% of diagnoses led to their adoption (table A1).
Because the Death Registry for our benchmark study is available until December 2016, the N-year survival indicator needs to forgo N years of the combined data. After the first diagnosis, more than 80% of cancer patients survive beyond 180 days, and about 60% live more than 3 years.
One concern about the data is that doctors may have diagnosed physician-patients with advanced cancer earlier than other patients, which would result in overstating physician-patients’ treatment and survival advantages. However, there is no evidence of this in the statistics (table A1). Our analysis includes all of the hospital admissions of first-diagnosis advanced cancer patients. The first diagnosis of physician-patients is about 3 percentage points more likely to be advanced than other cancer patients. This drops below 0.7 percentage points (with a standard error of 0.009 clustered at patient levels; not shown in the tables) after holding constant the patient’s sex, age, income, region, spending on inpatient care, and diagnosis year. These results suggest that our data are unlikely to contain potential bias due to earlier diagnoses by physician-patients.
Hospital admissions of physician- and nonphysician-patients with advanced cancer are compared in table 1, with standard errors clustered at patient levels. These data cover 1,123,377 admissions associated with 279,399 nonphysician-patients and 2,454 associated with 611 physician-patients. Given the closed-staff structure of Taiwanese hospitals, each admission matches one attending doctor to one patient. Statistics indicate that physician-patients are older and wealthier, tend to be male, and have spent less on hospital care before the first cancer diagnosis. Both physician- and nonphysician-patients are equally likely to have a preexisting clinical relationship with a doctor, but physician-patients tend to opt for male or more experienced doctors practicing in single locations and specializing in a cancer-related area or working in a cancer-related department.
Nonphysician-patients wait an average of 122 days to receive inpatient treatment after the first diagnosis, which is 5.59 days longer than physician-patients. This difference is significant at the 90% level. Nonphysician-patients also stay in acute inpatient care units for about 7.89 days, while physician-patient stays are 10% (0.81 days) shorter at the 95% significance level.
The unconditional mean difference tests in table 1 show that physician-patients are less likely to undergo surgery and chemotherapy by 8% and 5% (0.05/0.66; 0.04/0.8) but considerably more likely to use targeted treatment by 44% (0.05/0.11). However, these gaps may be due to different health or socioeconomic conditions or the selection of doctors with different practice styles.
Finally, the bottom part of table 1 shows that physician-patients have the same 180-day survival rate as other patients. However, their 1- and 3-year survival rates are higher, possibly due to higher income, better health, better communication, closer relationships with attending doctors, selection of doctors, or more cancer-related knowledge. The higher survival rate of mainly older male physician-patients than other patients with advanced cancer seems inconsistent.
III. Core Estimates
This section estimates the total effect on treatment choice and health outcomes. We adopt nearest-neighbor matching methods to address patient selection for unobserved doctor quality by contrasting physician-patients and comparable nonphysician-patients attended by the same doctor in the same hospital. Patients are precisely matched by type to ensure patient comparability.4 Since the method nonparametrically matches admissions by patient types and time components within doctor-hospital, both time-variant and time-invariant differences are captured in doctor and hospital quality and complex interactions among these covariates.5 Balanced statistics and matching estimates are presented in the next sections.
A. Balance Checks
First, the attending doctor is left unmatched, and nonphysician-patients and physician-patients of the same patient type in the same hospital are compared. Table 3 shows the balance checks for two matching schemes: scheme A (left) considers the exact match for patient kinds within hospitals, and scheme B (right) looks at those within doctor-hospital. Scheme A excludes 98% of nonphysician-patients and 84% of physician-patients because of nonoverlap in the covariate cells. Overlap is extremely rare in matching physician-patients with other patients with advanced cancer because physician-patients are significantly older, healthier, wealthier, and more masculine. After matching, the total number of admissions is 2,811, comprising 685 admissions (for 98 matched physician-patients) versus 2,126 admissions (for 565 matched nonphysician-patients).
Scheme A: Exact Match on Patient Types within Hospital | Scheme B: Exact Match on Patient Types within Doctor-Hospital | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SMD | t-test | KS Test | SMD | t-test | KS Test | |
Predetermined variables not matched on: | ||||||
Doctor gender | .14 | .88 | .00 | .00 | 1.00 | 1.00 |
Doctor experience at admission | .30 | .02 | .10 | −.04 | .92 | 1.00 |
Doctor selectivity at first diagnosis | .15 | .49 | .67 | −.04 | .90 | .97 |
Work in multiple hospitals | −.14 | .26 | .00 | .00 | 1.00 | 1.00 |
Patient’s log prior spending on drugs | −.01 | .87 | 1.00 | −.01 | .99 | 1.00 |
Patient’s pretrend in hospital cost | −.07 | .55 | 1.00 | −.01 | .95 | 1.00 |
Number/percentage of admissions | 2,811 | .26% | 552 | .05% | ||
Number of physician-patients | 98 | 31 | ||||
Number of nonphysician-patients | 565 | 69 | ||||
Number of admissions by physician-patients | 685 | 252 | ||||
Number of admissions by nonphysician-patients | 2,126 | 300 | ||||
Number of hospitals | 19 | 13 | ||||
Number of attending doctors | 441 | 28 | ||||
Number of hospital-doctor pairs | 443 | 28 | ||||
Admission counts by cancer site: | ||||||
Lip, oral cavity, or pharynx | 128 | 45 | ||||
Digestive organs and peritoneum | 1,307 | 238 | ||||
Respiratory system and chest cavity | 115 | 23 | ||||
Bones, skins, and connective and other subcutaneous tissues | 472 | 143 | ||||
Breast, reproductive, and urinary organs | 305 | 67 | ||||
Others (e.g., eyes, central nerves, endocrine glands, leukemias) | 484 | 36 |
Although scheme A narrows down comparable patients, these patients are mostly attended by different doctors; hence, the varied outcomes observed between physician-patients and other patients may be due to physician quality. We improve the balance of matches by further matching attending doctors in scheme B, which reduces the sample size to 552 admissions. Of these admissions, 252 are for 31 physician-patients and 300 are for 69 nonphysician-patients.
The balance tests for variables we did not match are shown in table 3, in which the p-values of the mean difference (t-tests) and distributional difference (Kolmogorov-Smirnov [KS] tests) are reported. Both tests have p-values equal to 1 for the precisely matched covariates. Scheme A statistics indicate that patients’ prediagnosis health conditions, estimated by pretrends in inpatient costs and prior drug spending, are balanced statistically. In contrast, doctors who treated physician-patients have 0.3 standard deviations more experience than those who treated nonphysician-patients. The distribution of the doctor’s gender, mobility, and specialties differs significantly between physician- and nonphysician-patients.
After matching patients according to their attending doctors in scheme B, none of these prediagnosis attributes indicate significant gaps in sample means or distributions. This result strongly suggests that matching attending doctors substantially improves the balance of observables, making it plausible that unobserved confounders also balance out.
B. Matching Estimates
Table 4 reports the matching estimates for the two matching schemes: within-hospital comparison between 2,811 matched admissions (scheme A) and within-doctor-hospital comparison between 552 matched entries (scheme B). The standard deviation in outcomes is displayed in columns 1 and 5 after removing the variation of the matched covariates. Further matching those 2,811 admissions with attending doctors in scheme B reduces the standard deviation by 15%–75%. This indicates that many of the changes in outcome are due to the variation in attending doctors.
Within-Hospital SD (1) | Scheme A: Exact Match by Patient Types within Hospital | Scheme B: Exact Match by Patient Types within Doctor-Hospital | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SD (2) | Coef (3) | SE (4) | SD (5) | Coef (6) | SE (7) | ||
Acute inpatient stays (days) | 12.1 | 9.6 | −1.9*** | .4 | 6.2 | −1.5*** | .4 |
Diagnosis-to-treatment (days) | 95.7 | 89.0 | 2.7 | 4.7 | 75.6 | 1.3 | 7.1 |
Cancer therapy: | |||||||
Surgery | .47 | .26 | .007 | .008 | .20 | −.083*** | .02 |
Radiation therapy | .46 | .40 | .016*** | .013 | .33 | −.071*** | .027 |
Chemotherapy | .39 | .28 | .034 | .010 | .20 | −.007 | .018 |
Targeted therapy | .31 | .27 | .109*** | .009 | .28 | .167*** | .024 |
Palliative care | .35 | .23 | −.024*** | .007 | .16 | −.027** | .013 |
Log spending: | |||||||
Total NHI cost | 1.52 | 1.91 | −.081 | .161 | 1.67 | −.055 | .179 |
Coinsurance | 2.20 | 1.66 | −.193* | .113 | 1.07 | −.226*** | .100 |
NHI drugs | 2.15 | 2.31 | .240 | .157 | 1.80 | .652*** | .165 |
Surgery | 4.21 | 3.89 | −.712*** | .248 | 2.87 | −1.159*** | .275 |
Tube feeding | 2.01 | 1.54 | −.277*** | .050 | .39 | −.031 | .022 |
Radiation therapy | 2.77 | 2.58 | −.307** | .153 | 2.00 | .128 | .185 |
Examination | 2.92 | 2.91 | −.480*** | .170 | 2.29 | −.943*** | .211 |
Survival: | |||||||
Lived ≥180 days | .25 | .18 | .008 | .006 | .11 | .025*** | .009 |
Lived ≥365 days | .39 | .31 | .045*** | .010 | .19 | .093*** | .015 |
Lived ≥1,095 days | .49 | .39 | .134*** | .015 | .20 | .071*** | .021 |
Number of admissions | 1,100,301 | 2,811 | 552 | ||||
Lived ≥180 days | 1,078,870 | 2,785 | 531 | ||||
Lived ≥365 days | 1,030,972 | 2,785 | 531 | ||||
Lived ≥1,095 days | 816,817 | 1,926 | 346 |
As scheme A does not match the hospital entries according to attending doctors, physician-patients tend to see more experienced and selective doctors than their nonphysician counterparts in this scheme (table 3). Suppose that physician-patients prefer fewer tests and fewer intensive therapies at the advanced cancer stage and that experienced or highly qualified doctors tend to choose more intensive types of care and order more tests.6 As physicians can more easily identify highly skilled doctors than nonphysicians, we understate physician-patients’ negative impact on intensive care utilization and checkup costs if we do not match them according to their attending doctors.
Matching hospital entries according to attending doctors and hospitals in scheme B dramatically increases physician-patients’ surgical/radiation adoption and costs for examinations, as expected. Physician-patients are 8 percentage points less likely to undergo surgery and 7 percentage points less likely to choose radiation therapy. These statistically significant estimates account for 42% and 21% of the residual standard deviation (0.083/0.20; 0.071/0.33). In contrast, scheme B reduces the margins of intensive care. Physician-patients’ tube-feeding care drops from approximately 0.3 to 0.03 percentage points. The effect of radiation also substantially decreases and becomes statistically insignificant. These impacts of different treatments on physician-patients’ survival within-hospital and within-doctor-hospital matched samples suggest that physician-patients pick better doctors, even within hospitals.
Our benchmark (scheme B) shows that physician-patients are significantly less likely to adopt surgery by 0.4 standard deviations (0.083/0.20) and radiation therapy by 0.2 standard deviations (0.071/0.33). As for intensive margins, physician-patients utilize surgery less frequently than their counterparts by 0.4 standard deviations (1.159/2.87) while taking approximately the same radiation dose. In addition, while using less intensive care, physician-patients with advanced cancer are less likely to adopt palliative care by 0.2 standard deviations (0.027/0.16). The only items physician-patients utilize more are targeted drug therapy ( more likely) and prescription medication ( standard deviations greater costs).
Physician-patients with advanced cancer spend more on medication, but the source of the spending rise cannot be determined from the currently available data. The higher spending could be due to greater quantities, more varieties, or increased drug prices (e.g., on patented brands). Doctors/hospitals cannot charge different prices for the same drugs because of universally uniform reimbursement prices and adjustments (Chen and Chuang 2016). This institutional feature leaves physician-patients’ increased drug dose or variety as the likely explanation for their increased medication cost.7
C. Cost-Effectiveness
According to the American Cancer Association’s published medical guidelines, surgery/radiation therapies are more appropriate for early-stage cancers. More advanced cancer requires treatment that reaches the entire body (e.g., chemotherapy and targeted drug therapy). We have shown that physician-patients receive less surgery/radiation treatment for advanced cancer than the matched nonphysician-patients while spending more on drugs and being more likely to use targeted therapy. If physician-patients’ treatment is clinically suitable, our results indicate that underuse and overuse coexist among nonphysician-patients.
Physician-patients receive different and better treatment, significantly increasing their chances of short-term survival compared with other patients by 2.5 (9.3) percentage points at 180- and 365-day thresholds, as shown in columns 6 and 7 of table 4. Their long-term survival is also higher by 7.1 percentage points at the 3-year cutoff. These estimates account for at least 0.25 standard deviations. Besides the survival benefit of better treatment, physician-patients pay significantly less for coinsurance by 0.226 log points. Overall, physician-patients receive cost-effective care relative to that given to matched patients.
IV. Competing Explanations
Several theories could explain physician-patients’ intensive care decline and their increased chances of survival, which may be driven by physician-patient relational or informational benefits. Three alternative explanations for the observed decline in physician-patients’ intensive care volume may be that they are diagnosed with cancer earlier or receive cancer therapies earlier than others, that they exhibit better health than nonphysician-patients, or that they are more likely to sue for malpractice. Each explanation is examined below.
A. Physician-Patients Are Diagnosed Earlier or Treated Earlier
Physician-patient relationships and informational advantages may lead to earlier diagnoses or treatment than for nonphysician-patients, resulting in the former needing less intensive care and surviving longer. However, the hypothesis that the physician-patient status reduces the likelihood of being diagnosed too late cannot be accepted, as discussed in section II.D.
The matching estimates for scheme B in table 4 show that physician-patients wait 1.3 days longer than other patients between diagnosis and treatment. This difference is statistically insignificant and accounts for less than 2% (1.3/75.6) of a standard deviation. Hence, the hypothesis that physician-patients receive treatment earlier than nonphysician-patients cannot be accepted.
B. Physician-Patients Exhibit Better Health
To ensure that the matched physicians and other patients have similar health conditions, we compare only patients in the same quintile for hospital spending in the 3 years before being diagnosed with advanced cancer. However, it remains possible that physician-patients are healthier than their counterparts in a way not captured by our model. We test this hypothesis by checking the balance of variables excluded from the covariate list. The placebo test results in table 3 are contrary to this hypothesis. The matched patients’ previous drug spending and pretrend hospital costs are not significantly different. This pattern is robust, irrespective of scheme A or B (accounting for the attending doctor or not) if limited to matched patients in the same hospitals who share the same attributes and cancer sites during the same admission period. This result suggests that physician-patients’ better health is not due to reduced surgical/radiation treatment before diagnosis.
C. Physician-Patients Are Less Likely to Sue for Malpractice than Other Patients
Another explanation for our finding of physician-patients’ reduced intensive care and examinations is that they are less likely than nonphysician-patients to sue for malpractice. Currie and MacLeod (2008) suggest that potential liability concerns may induce doctors to perform more unnecessary procedures, especially for nonphysician-patients in our context. We examine this explanation by investigating the frequency of malpractice lawsuits for our matched data.
During our data period (2004–16), medical doctors in Taiwan were subject to no-fault or joint and several liability (Ministry of Health and Welfare 2018). ER doctors, neurosurgeons, and anesthesiologists were most likely to be sued and pay noneconomic damages (Chen et al. 2012). On investigating our matched data to see whether physician-patients in the riskiest departments receive exceptionally high premiums, we found almost no physician-patients with cancer seeking care in these departments. As a result, there is no evidence that the lower utilization rates of surgical or radiation therapy of physician-patients with advanced cancer could be explained by defensive medicine. Nevertheless, fear of litigation may still drive some doctors to prescribe different types of procedures to physician-patients than nonphysician-patients due to unobserved differences, which we will address next.
V. Informational versus Relational Mechanisms
In this section, we further restrict our data to physician-patients only to probe the effect of professional ties and medical knowledge on treatment and survival.8 We aim to extract parts of the physician-patient impact driven by relational advantages that previous researchers have often interpreted as informational. This task is possible because the attending doctors in our data have a wide range of (sub)specialties. We examine various specialties among doctors and physician-patient to distinguish between the relational and informational channels.
One noteworthy data limitation is that in Taiwan the government regulates board certification for 23 specialties, but it does not specify any rules for subspecialty certification. The absence of regulation leaves subspecialty certification at the discretion of medical associations outside the NHI database scope. Consequently, we observe doctors’ first/primary specialty, not their subspecialties.
Taiwan’s cancer care specialization structure parallels Japan’s pre-2007 medical system before Japan enacted the Cancer Control Act.9 While doctors in the United States refer cancer patients to oncologists, Taiwanese organ-specific specialists diagnose and remove operable cancer using endoscopic procedures or refer inoperable cancer patients to oncologists for chemotherapy or radiation treatment. Thus, doctors in Taiwan attending to stomach cancer patients could be gastroenterologists, gastrointestinal surgeons, or radiation oncologists, and we cannot determine whether these specialists have a certified oncology subspecialty.10
A. Relational Mechanism: Mapping Specialists to Social Networks
As the attending doctor is fully responsible for caring for each admitted patient under Taiwanese NHI’s closed staff structure, each doctor-patient pair has a well-defined professional connection. Physician-patients who share the doctor’s specialty have a stronger tie because they may have met professionally before the diagnosis. Since subspecialties are unobservable in our data, we can infer patient-doctor networks from physician specialties, TOS taxonomy classification, and the doctor’s hospital department. We follow the TOS taxonomy to classify networks, allowing one doctor to have multiple networks, and summarize how we map specialists according to a social network in table 2.
TOS covers eight of the top 10 cancer treatment specialties: three from the medical oncology network (category I, cols. 1–3) and six from the surgical oncology network (category II, cols. 3–8), with radiation oncology belonging to both networks (col. 3).11 Although TOS lists pathologists as part of the medical oncology network, we separate from the medical oncology network those without another specialty and those who have never worked in internal medicine departments. However, despite having no medical knowledge of or caseload involving cancer treatment, TOS-listed plastic and reconstructive surgeons are included as part of the surgical oncology network because of the double-dose surgical training required for them to become board-certified surgical oncologists. Finally, although dermatologists and ophthalmologists who treat most skin/eye cancers are excluded from the TOS taxonomy (cols. 9, 10), we assume that they have separate networks unrelated to cancer care in areas denoted by “others.”
B. Informational Mechanism: Mapping Specialists to Medical Knowledge of a Cancer Site
We estimate physician-patients’ medical knowledge of their cancer site using the caseload per doctor in the same specialty relative to the highest volume. Table A3 illustrates our estimation process for advanced breast cancer. First, we calculate the caseload per doctor by specialty and hospital department using 100% inpatient reimbursement data (col. 1); then we measure the relative knowledge/caseload of the cancer site per specialty across hospital departments (col. 2). The top breast cancer experts are surgeons in surgery departments with the highest caseload, while doctors in other departments/specialties account for only a fraction of the top expert caseload.
Physician-patients’ previous workplaces or hospital departments are unobservable. We then estimate their knowledge of the cancer site given their first specialty in column 3 by averaging the relative caseloads per specialty across departments, weighted by department shares. The mapping of each cancer site to specialty-specific knowledge is summarized in table 2. For example, the top advanced breast cancer experts are surgeons in surgery departments whose knowledge level of this cancer is 0.49, far below 1, since most surgeons working in departments rarely treat breast cancer. This data feature is common among other specialists (e.g., radiation oncologists).
We apply this method to all cancer sites. Surgeons with specialties not listed in the columns have zero relative knowledge/caseload (e.g., neurologists, neurosurgeons, and plastic and reconstructive surgeons). The statistics show that the top cancer experts are typically organ-specific specialists (except for bone cancer), and radiation oncologists are the top leukemia and stomach cancer treatment experts. Finally, we standardize physician-patients’ knowledge levels of their cancer site.
C. Exploration of Mechanisms
Using the network indicator R and continuous information measure K constructed in sections V.A and V.B, we evaluate the relative contributions of relational and informational advantages to cancer treatment and patient survival. Let denote physician-patients’ heterogeneous impact on outcomes given their network R and knowledge K. We assume that the full effect can be broken into four components:
To evaluate these mechanisms, we first identify the physician status effect (β) by comparing nonphysician-patients and physician-patients with no advantage. Second, we estimate the total impact of a professional tie with the attending doctor (), including the network’s main effect and the network-induced informational effect (), so relational and informational mechanisms are both at work. We cannot separate these two effects using matching methods due to the lack of support of continuous medical knowledge.12 We overcome this challenge in the third step by estimating the value of a network by information percentile when applying fixed effects models to matched physician-patients. Each step is expanded, as shown below.
1. Physician-Patients’ General Advantage over Nonphysician-Patients
Using scheme B’s procedure, we first identify β, the physician status effect, by matching nonphysician-patients and physician-patients with no advantage. Before matching, physicians with no advantage tend to be older but healthier males and are more likely to seek care from a more experienced doctor than other patients (table A4, cols. 1, 2). After matching by doctor-hospital and patient types (n. 4), we obtain a near-perfect balance between nonphysician-patients and physician-patients with no specific advantage. With these stringent data requirements, only 5.6% of physician-patients (168/3,013) are matched to 106 comparable nonphysician-patients treated by 17 doctors in seven hospitals (not shown in the tables).
The matching estimates are presented in table 5, and the coefficients are boldfaced with patterns resembling the average physician-patient effect. Physician-patients with no advantage have fewer examinations, significantly less surgery, and shorter stays in acute inpatient care while spending much more than nonphysician-patients on medication (cols. 2, 3), consistent with the average physician-patient effect (cols. 8, 9, copied from table 4). However, unlike average physician-patients, physician-patients with no advantage have a probability of targeted therapy 6.0 percentage points lower but a probability of chemotherapy 9.4 percentage points higher than that of nonphysician-patients. Both estimates are highly statistically significant, representing more than half of the variation in utilization. Surprisingly, this substantially different treatment due to physician status shows no survival advantage (bottom of cols. 2, 3).
Scheme B: Matching Nonphysician-Patients to Physician-Patients with No Advantage | Scheme C: Matching of Physician-Patients | Baseline Scheme B | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SD (1) | Physician Status Effect (β) | SD (4) | Total Relational Effect () | SD (7) | Average Physician-Patient Effect () | ||||
Coef (2) | SE (3) | Coef (5) | SE (6) | Coef (8) | SE (9) | ||||
Acute inpatient stays (days) | 3.7 | −1.3** | .5 | 5.8 | −2.5 | 2.2 | 6.2 | −1.5*** | .4 |
Diagnosis to treatment (days) | 65.9 | −2.3 | 11.6 | 86.7 | 5.7 | 11.0 | 75.6 | 1.3 | 7.1 |
Cancer therapy: | |||||||||
Surgery | .23 | −.088** | .037 | .34 | .087** | .043 | .20 | −.083*** | .018 |
Radiation | .36 | .011 | .048 | .31 | .194*** | .058 | .33 | −.071*** | .027 |
Chemotherapy | .16 | .094*** | .023 | .22 | .253*** | .041 | .20 | −.007 | .018 |
Targeted | .10 | −.060*** | .016 | .38 | −.151*** | .044 | .28 | .167*** | .024 |
Palliative care | .12 | .060*** | .016 | .19 | −.249*** | .026 | .16 | −.027** | .013 |
Log spending: | |||||||||
Total NHI cost | 1.67 | .028 | .286 | 1.32 | −.408 | .269 | 1.67 | −.055 | .179 |
Coinsurance | 1.08 | −.165 | .192 | 1.70 | −.580** | .283 | 1.07 | −.226*** | .100 |
NHI drugs | 1.73 | .770*** | .270 | 1.45 | −.270 | .262 | 1.80 | .652*** | .165 |
Surgery | 3.29 | −1.512*** | .459 | 2.81 | −.379 | .654 | 2.87 | −1.159*** | .275 |
Tube feeding | .00 | NA | .76 | −.323 | .436 | .39 | −.031 | .022 | |
Radiation therapy | 1.81 | .771*** | .285 | 2.13 | −.510 | .378 | 2.00 | .128 | .185 |
Examination | 2.31 | −1.502*** | .315 | 2.35 | .057 | .582 | 2.29 | −.943*** | .211 |
Survival: | |||||||||
Lived ≥180 days | +.00 | +.000 | .000 | .15 | .001 | .029 | .11 | .025*** | .009 |
Lived ≥365 days | +.00 | +.000 | .000 | .22 | −.008 | .040 | .19 | .093*** | .015 |
Lived ≥1,095 days | .20 | −.007 | .034 | .28 | .252*** | .077 | .20 | .071*** | .021 |
Number of admissions | 217 | 277 | 552 | ||||||
Lived ≥180 days | 180 | 244 | 531 | ||||||
Lived ≥365 days | 180 | 237 | 531 | ||||||
Lived ≥1,095 days | 146 | 178 | 346 |
2. Total Impact of Professional Network
The network’s main effect (ρ) must be compared with the knowledge’s main effect (E[e(K)]) to determine the relative importance of relational versus informational mechanisms. This task requires a balanced sample of physician-patients with networks but no relevant knowledge versus those with relevant knowledge but no networks. However, as this approach requires immense data support and stronger assumptions because the knowledge is continuous, instead we estimate , the total impact of the professional network, including its main effect ρ and the network-induced informational effect E[δ(K)].13
We address the selection issue with a nonrandom assignment of professional ties by focusing on inpatient doctors who attend multiple comparable physician-patients with different relational advantages. We match these highly homogeneous patients precisely according to scheme C, by doctor-hospital and patient types (gender, cancer sites, and previous hospital spending terciles). Furthermore, we also control their age, income, prior trends of inpatient spending, and doctor experience in the matching procedure.14
If patients select doctors based on doctor quality and patient attributes and preferences, we can minimize selection bias by looking at these precisely matched physician-patients. As doctor-patient matches are independent decisions patients make using private information on preference and doctor quality, we can use patient choices to infer these unobservables for bias correction. Hence, our identification relies on assuming self-selection on observables and unobservables to minimize the possibility of reverse causality, as confirmed by our placebo tests.
The total networking impact and average physician-patient effect are shown to be opposite for intensive care and drug use in matching scheme C (cols. 5 and 6 vs. 8 and 9, table 5). Networking induces more than 0.25 standard deviations (0.087/0.34) more surgery, radiation, and chemotherapy utilization while reducing target therapy by 0.40 standard deviations (0.151/0.38). In contrast, typical physician-patients are less likely to receive intensive care but use increased targeted therapy and medication instead.15
Neither physician status nor networking explains why typical physician-patients tend to replace intensive care with targeted therapy while enjoying better short-term survival rates (180 or 365 days; see cols. 2 and 3 vs. 5 and 6). On the one hand, this implies that the informational mechanism is the main driver of intensive care reduction and short-term survival improvement at the advanced stage; on the other hand, the total network effect is consistent with the impact of average physician-patients on coinsurance, palliative care, and 3-year survival rates (cols. 5, 6). A strong professional tie with the attending doctor reduces coinsurance costs and the need for palliative care, with a chance of 3 years’ survival more than 0.28 standard deviations (0.071/0.252). These concurrent results suggest that the network-related channels correctly project the different coinsurance costs, palliative care, and 3-year survival rates of physician-patients and nonphysician-patients.
3. Interchangeability between Network and Knowledge
Although the average physician-patient effect on some treatments is consistent with the impact of physician status or network-related mechanisms, neither of these elements explains why average physician-patients tend to replace radiation with targeted therapies while enjoying better short-term survival than nonphysician-patients. This suggests that this information is crucial in determining treatment and survival. Using equation (1), we quantify the value of a network by information percentiles using the degree of informational interchangeability for a network, that is, how many more medical knowledge percentiles are required to maintain the same survival or treatment intensity if the physician-patient lacks a robust professional tie with the attending doctor. Our parameter of interest is
We perform fixed effects regressions with two causal variables, network and knowledge, by combining two balanced samples to derive sufficient variation: one balancing patients with versus without a network (as shown in cols. 1–3 of table A5), and the other balancing knowledge above versus below the median (cols. 4–6). We illustrate the data structure in table 6. The data balanced by networks has 277 observations, which overlaps the data balanced by knowledge in 214 cases. The data balanced by knowledge adds 80 extra admissions that are not balanced by network(s).
All Physician-Patients | All Physician-Patients | Total | |
---|---|---|---|
Not Matched | Matched Subsample for Patients With versus Without a Network | ||
Not matched | 2,656 | 63 | 2,719 |
Matched subsample for patients with knowledge above vs. below the 50th percentile | 80 | 214 | 294 |
Total | 2,736 | 277 | 3,013 |
Using this integrated sample, we estimate that the fixed effects model holds the same list of covariates constant as in scheme C of section V.C.1. Although the estimated coefficients are imprecise (tables A6-1, A6-2) due to the limited support of continuous information, there are clear patterns in the estimated value of networks. We sketch the interchangeability of a given network in figures 1–3, as the case with no network, , is too noisy.
We find a strikingly persistent pattern. Lacking relevant knowledge of the cancer site makes networking equivalent to knowledge reduction. The value of networking for most outcomes, when the knowledge level is at or below the bottom quartile, is significantly negative, between −11 and −6 percentage points. It further expands to −18 and −14 percentage points at the bottom 1st percentile. For professionally connected but less informed patients, the social tie is equivalent to losing 15–18 percentage points of relevant knowledge of the cancer site to maintain the same survival or treatment intensity. This result affects survival rates, examination costs (fig. 1), use of surgery/radiation therapy at extensive and intensive margins (fig. 2), adoption of target drug therapy, and drug/tube-feeding costs (fig. 3). Palliative care and chemotherapy are exceptions for which we obtained insufficient precision.
In summary, when doctors attend to professionally connected physician-patients with no relevant knowledge, they may abuse the trust of these patients by deviating from the treatment they would prescribe to a knowledgeable specialist-patient, harming their chance of survival.
VI. Conclusions
The agency problem plays a leading role in understanding health-care inequality. Researchers have found evidence consistent with the hypothesis of doctor-driven demand and the consequence of asymmetric information in treatment. However, less is known about how the doctor-patient relationship mitigates agency concerns. Some evidence has shown that social ties lessen agency issues in preventive care or cesarean section utilization, but the relevance of the doctor-patient relationship in mitigating agency issues remains unknown outside those contexts.
This paper began with a benchmark of physicians treating physicians without separating relational and informational mechanisms. We compared treatments and survival outcomes of physician-patients and nonphysician-patients with the same advanced cancer, attending doctor, and hospital. We exploited the within-doctor-hospital variation to compare exactly matched patients. Using rich controls, we addressed patient selection and unobserved doctor quality. The results show that physician-patients require less intensive care and receive more medication, more targeted therapy, and fewer checkups, all of which cost less and improve survival.17
Physician-patients have clinical knowledge and professional connections, which potentially contribute to better care and higher survival rates than nonphysician-patients. We extended the matching method to evaluate the importance of relational and informational advantages by exploiting various medical specialties among physician-patients and their attending doctors. Physician-patients who possess neither advantage induce the attending doctor to prescribe different treatments (e.g., less surgery, more medication, and fewer tests), which do not prolong their lives relative to nonphysician-patients. In data restricted to physician-patients, a stronger doctor-patient relationship induces more intensive care and improves long-term survival, consistent with the average physician-patient effect. Nevertheless, neither physician status nor professional tie explains why average physician-patients tend to replace radiation with targeted therapies and enjoy a better short-term survival rate. This leaves the informational mechanism as the leading explanation for the result.
To confirm, we estimated the value of a professional tie relative to medical knowledge using more restrictive models. A professional connection equates to a knowledge reduction if physician-patients are less informed, and this tends to lower their chance of survival as they receive treatment different from that prescribed to specialist patients who possess relevant medical knowledge and experience of their diagnosed cancer.
The revealed mechanisms are consistent with a framework in which doctors can induce demand to benefit their self-interest. A stronger patient-doctor bond builds trust, which the latter may exploit to induce demand if patients are less informed, as posited by the classic doctor-driven demand hypothesis.
These findings offer lessons for the labor markets of expert services (e.g., real estate agencies, used car dealerships, and initial public offering underwriting). The key to resolving agency problems is to close the information gap between principals and agents. Professional connections intensify agency issues if consumers are less informed. Better information increases the chance of belonging to a network, which generates more information. Professional ties can benefit only expert consumers in the long term when networking provides insider information. Essentially, relational advantages alone cannot eliminate conflicting interests.
Although our analytical approach is novel, our study has three limitations. First, it assumes that relational and informational advantages are monotonic. In other words, the comparison made by distinguishing doctor-patient pairs by medical specialties is the same as separating physician-patients from nonphysician-patients. However, professional connections via medical association networks may differ from social ties via occupations in affecting treatment and survival rates. Second, we assume that physician-patients’ choice of professional networks is fully captured by observables. If their choice is also based on unobservable incentives independent of those observed, we have overstated the relational benefits and understated the informational advantages due to reverse causation. Physician-patients who prefer intensive care may choose a doctor with whom they have a relational advantage to receive favorable treatment.18
Finally, the matched sample size is small because of the rare overlap between physician-patients and nonphysician-patients and among physician-patients by advantage. Nearest-neighbor matching may not fully eliminate bias given a modest set of controls for patient types (n. 4), although precisely matching patients by doctor-hospital substantially reduces it. Our understanding of the impact of networking-induced information on patient survival would be significantly enhanced by more available data. We aim to increase our observations and relax the monotonicity assumption in future research.
Notes
We thank the Health and Welfare Data Science Center (HWDC) at Taiwan’s Ministry of Health and Welfare for providing the administrative data. The study received institutional review board approval from NTUH-REC 201911059W and 202111058W. We also thank Nicolas Acosta, Janet Currie, Joseph Doyle, Mark Duggan, Albert Park, Hitoshi Shigeoka, Michael Waldman, and Hannes Ullrich for their comments. Special thanks to Ji-Wen Chen of the National Taiwan University Hospital for administrative assistance. We acknowledge funding from a University of Tokyo’s startup research grant, a Japan Center for Economic Research Award (201500000037), a National Chengchi University’s research grant (111H112-03), and the Japan Center for Economic Research (JP17H02537, JP19K01670, JP17K13759, and JPJS-JRP20181403). All remaining errors are our own. Data availability statement: Researchers interested in using this database may apply to the HWDC for access. See the HWDC’s official website for details. Exemption from data availability requirements is mandatory. Contact the corresponding author, Stacey H. Chen, at [email protected]. Information concerning access to the data used in this paper is available in a zip file.
1 Alongside experimental designs, several observational studies have compared self-treatment with treating others to detect health-care agency problems (Bronnenberg et al. 2015; Carrera and Skipper 2017); Levitt and Syverson (2008) adopted the same approach to test for agency problems using expert-consumers. However, this comparison may capture the difference in the susceptibility of self-treatment vs. treating others, not necessarily reflecting the physician-patients’ effect on treatment choice (Ubel, Angott, and Zikmund-Fisher 2011; Shaban, Guerry, and Quill 2011). Earlier researchers avoided the susceptibility bias by comparing expert-consumers to nonexperts or physician-patients to other patients (Bunker and Brown 1974; Hay and Leahy 1982).
2 Frakes, Gruber, and Jena (2021) used data from the Military Health System and found that physician-patients received only slightly more medical care. The physician-patient effect potentially had relational advantages that may have canceled out the informational premium, leading to a near-zero effect. Leuven, Oosterbeek, and de Wolf (2013), Artmann, Oosterbeek, and Van Der Klaauw (2022), Chen, Persson, and Polyakova (2022), and Finkelstein et al. (2022) investigate the information effects by comparing outcomes of physicians’ relatives and those of comparable patients.
3 We identify hospital admission as “advanced cancer” if the cancer is invasive (the fifth digit of ), the patient has multiple cancer sites, or the cells are of a poorly differentiated anaplastic grade ( or 4; for colon, rectum, or ovary cancer, any GRADE value except B).
4 The following patient types are included: gender, 17 cancer sites, 2-year age bins, 4-year admission period, six residence regions, hospital spending quintile 4 years before diagnosis, income quintile in the year before the first diagnosis, and an indicator of a preexisting clinical relationship with the attending doctor 3 years before diagnosis.
5 To control for time components, hospital entries are precisely matched according to admission periods and the attending doctor’s 5-year experience at the time of diagnosis.
6 Previous researchers suggest that intensive care can prolong life. Balsa and McGuire (2003) and Currie, MacLeod, and Van Parys (2016) show that lung cancer or heart attack patients benefit from aggressive treatment via intensive procedures.
7 Whether our basic results derived from nonparametric matching are consistent with those using conventional fixed effects models is explored in the appendix. The matching method provides considerably more precise and robust estimates than fixed effects models using the same set of controls (table A2).
8 We include two additional years of NHID data on physician-patients in this section to increase the sample size.
9 See Minami (2012), Takiguchi, Sakaida, and Sekine (2012), and Tamura (2012).
10 This difference in specialization between US and Taiwanese medical systems may be due to Taiwan’s tight controls over hospital spending under a single-payer, global-budgeting system, which leaves little room for most hospitals to pay enough premiums to oncology subspecialists.
11 Since 1990, TOS has certified/renewed medical oncology and surgical oncology subspecialty licenses for eligible doctors. It separates trainees by their specialties (surgical vs. medical) for most events. Medical oncologists primarily treat cancer using medication (e.g., chemotherapy, immunotherapy, and targeted therapy), whereas surgical oncologists use surgical methods to remove operable cancers. Both categories include the Taiwan Society for Therapeutic Radiology and Oncology; we designate radiation oncologists to both professional networks. Although the Taiwan Neurosurgery Society is on the surgical oncology list, we cannot find a neurosurgeon who has treated a cancer physician-patient. Hence, we include neurosurgeons from the surgical oncology network, although we emphasize their zero knowledge of cancer treatment.
12 When we group physician-patients by their advantage (e.g., having a knowledge index below vs. above the median), the sample shrinks dramatically. The matched patients cluster among only one or two specific cancer sites, making it difficult to interpret.
13 A robust professional tie with the attending doctor can induce professional and general social interactions. Our identification cannot distinguish professional networks from general social interactions, as doctors in similar specialties interact for various reasons, not necessarily for professional networking.
14 We implement placebo tests to check whether the network indicator among matched physician-patients is nearly random. A balance between matched physician-patients with vs. without a network on those not precisely matched controls (e.g., age) is shown in cols. 1–3 of table A5. This confirms the validity of the exogeneity condition. Nevertheless, we include those controls and each physician-patient’s knowledge level in this matching scheme.
15 We omit hormone therapy from our analysis because it treats prostate and breast cancers. Given patient sex and cancer site, the data show almost no variation in doctor specialty, leaving the parameters of interest unidentified.
16 To see why, consider or given . The equality holds if and only if .
17 Physicians’ relatives may receive benefits similar to physician-patients. As relatives are considered as nonphysician-patients in this paper, our results may understate the physician premiums.
18 This limitation is the same as that faced by Reuter (2006), who attempted to evaluate favoritism in allocating initial public offering stocks (IPOs) across mutual fund families. He identifies the impact of this favoritism by controlling the level of private information using a proxy that varies across investor-underwriter relationships. However, the observed favoritism may be due to selection issues related to mutual fund managers’ incentive to strategically allocate underpriced IPOs (Gaspar, Massa, and Matos 2006).
References
Abadie, Alberto, and Guildo W. Imbens. 2006. Large sample properties of matching estimators for average treatment effects. Econometrica 74:235–67. ———. 2011. Bias-corrected matching estimators for average treatment effects. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 29:1–11. Alsan, Marcella, Owen Garrick, and Grant Graziani. 2019. Does diversity matter for health? Experimental evidence from Oakland. American Economic Review 109, no. 12:4071–111. Artmann, Elisabeth, Hessel Oosterbeek, and Bas Van Der Klaauw. 2022. Do doctors improve the health care of their parents? Evidence from admission lotteries. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 14, no. 3:164–84. Balsa, An I., and Thomas G. McGuire. 2003. Prejudice, clinical uncertainty, and stereotyping as sources of health disparities. Journal of Health Economics 22:89–116. Bandiera, Oriana, Iwan Barankay, and Imran Rasul. 2009. Social connections and incentives in the workplace: Evidence from personnel data. Econometrica 77, no. 4:1047–94. Bronnenberg, Bart J., Jean-Pierre Dub’e, Matthew Gentzkow, and Jesse M. Shapiro. 2015. Do pharmacists buy Bayer? Informed shoppers and the brand premium. Quarterly Journal of Economics 130, no. 4:1669–726. Bunker, John P., and Byron Wm. Brown Jr. 1974. The physician-patient as an informed consumer of surgical services. New England Journal of Medicine 290, no. 19:1051–55. Carrera, Mariana, and Niels Skipper. 2017. Physicians are more likely than non-physicians to use brand-name drugs to treat their chronic conditions. Journal of Epidemiology Community Health 71:874–81. Chen, Kuan-Yu, Che-Ming Yang, Shin-Han Tsai, Hung-Yi Chiou, Mau-Roung Lin, and Wen-Ta Chiu. 2012. Medical malpractice in Taiwan: Injury types, compensation, and specialty risk. Academic Emergency Medicine 19, no. 5:598–600. Chen, Stacey H., and Hongwei Chuang. 2016. Recent trends in Taiwanese medical spending. Fiscal Studies 37, no. 3/4:653–88. Chen, Yiqun, Petra Persson, and Maria Polyakova. 2022. The roots of health inequality and the value of intrafamily expertise. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 14, no. 3:185–223. Chou, Yiing-Jenq, Nicole Huang, I-Feng Lin, Chung-Yeh Deng, Yi-Wen Tsai, Long-Shen Chen, and Cheng-Hua Lee. 2006. Do physicians and their relatives have a decreased rate of cesarean section? A 4-year population-based study in Taiwan. Birth 33, no. 3:195–202. Currie, Janet, and W. Bentley MacLeod. 2008. First do no harm? Tort reform and birth outcomes. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, no. 2:795–830. Currie, Janet, W. Bentley MacLeod, and Jessica Van Parys. 2016. Physician practice style and patient health outcomes: The case of heart attacks. Journal of Health Economics 47:64–80. Finkelstein, Amy, Petra Persson, Maria Polyakova, and Jesse M. Shapiro. 2022. A taste of their own medicine: Guideline adherence and access to expertise. AER: Insights 4, no. 4:507–26. Frakes, Michael, Jonathan Gruber, and Anupam Jena. 2021. Is great information good enough? Evidence from physicians as patients. Journal of Health Economics 75:102406. Gaspar, José-Miguel, Massimo Massa, and Pedro Matos. 2006. Favoritism in mutual fund families? Evidence on strategic cross-fund subsidization. Journal of Finance 61, no. 1:73–104. Grytten, Jostein, Irene Skau, and Rune Sørensen. 2011. Do expert patients get better treatment than others? Agency discrimination and statistical discrimination in obstetrics. Journal of Health Economics 30, no. 1:163–80. Hay, Joel, and Michael J. Leahy. 1982. Physician-induced demand: An empirical analysis of the consumer information gap. Journal of Health Economics 1, no. 3:231–44. Jackson, C. Kirabo, and Henry S. Schneider. 2011. Do social connections reduce moral hazard? Evidence from the New York City taxi industry. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3:244–67. Johnson, Erin M., and M. Marit Rehavi. 2016. Physicians treating physicians: Information and incentives in childbirth. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 8, no. 1:115–41. Johnson, Erin M., M. Marit Rehavi, David C. Chan Jr., and Daniela Carusi. 2016. A doctor will see you now: Physician-patient relationships and clinical decisions. NBER Working Paper no. 22666, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Leuven, Edwin, Hessel Oosterbeek, and Inge de Wolf. 2013. The effects of medical school on health outcomes: Evidence from admission lotteries. Journal of Health Economics 32, no. 4:698–707. Levitt, Steven D., and Chad Syverson. 2008. Market distortions when agents are better informed: The value of information in real estate transactions. Review of Economics and Statistics 90, no. 4:599–611. Minami, Hironobu. 2012. Training oncologists in cross-specialty medical oncology. Annals of Oncology 23, no. 11:xi70. Ministry of Health and Welfare (Taiwan). 2018. Medical Care Act. Article 82. Amended on January 24, 2018. Reuter, Jonathan. 2006. Are IPO allocations for sale? Evidence from mutual funds. Journal of Finance 61, no. 5:2289–324. Shaban, Eric, Roshni Guerry, and Timothy E. Quill. 2011. Reconciling physician bias and recommendations. Archives of Internal Medicine 171, no. 7:634–35. Takiguchi, Yuichi, Emiko Sakaida, and Ikuo Sekine. 2012. Building infrastructure to train medical oncologists. Annals of Oncology 23, suppl. 11: xi69–70. Tamura, Kazuo. 2012. Cancer professional education plan and the subspecialty in oncology by the Japanese medical societies: The results, issues to be solved and perspectives. Annals of Oncology 23, suppl. 11: xi70. Ubel, Peter A., Andrea M. Angott, and Brian J. Zikmund-Fisher. 2011. Physicians recommend different treatments for patients than they would choose for themselves. Archives of Internal Medicine 171, no. 7:630–34.